Conway’s Law and Science

Conway’s Law is the observation that the structure of a product will reflect the structure of the organization that designed it. If the organization has three parts, so will the product. In the original paper (1968), Conway put it like this:

Any organization that designs a system (defined broadly) will produce a design whose structure is a copy of the organization’s communication structure.

Here is an example:

A contract research organization had eight people who were to produce a COBOL and an ALGOL compiler. After some initial estimates of difficulty and time, five people were assigned to the COBOL job and three to the ALGOL job. The resulting COBOL compiler ran in five phases, the ALG0L compiler ran in three.

A consumer — someone outside the organization who uses the product — wants the best design. Conway’s Law implies they are unlikely to get it.

I generalize Conway’s Law like this: It is hard for people with jobs to innovate — for reasons that outsiders know nothing about. Whereas persons without jobs have total freedom. An example is a politician who promises change but fails to deliver. The promises of change are plausible to outsiders (voters) so they elect the politician. However, being outsiders, they barely understand how government works. When the promised changes don’t happen, the voters are “disillusioned”.

To me, the most interesting application of the generalized law is to science. In my experience, people who complain about “bad science”, such as John Ioannides and Ben Goldacre, have the same incomplete view of the world as the “disillusioned” voters. They fail to grasp the constraints involved. They fail to consider that the science they are criticizing may be the best those professional scientists can produce, given the system within which they work. Better critiques would look at the constraints the professional scientists are under, the reasons for those constraints, and how those constraints might be overcome.

“Much research is conducted for reasons other than the pursuit of truth,” writes Ioannidis. Well, yes — people with jobs want to keep them and get promoted. They want to appear high status. That’s not going to change. It’s absolutely true that drug company scientists slant the evidence to favor their company’s drug, as Irving Kirsch explains in The Emperor’s New Drugs. But if you don’t understand what causes depression and you’re trying to produce a new anti-depressant and you want to keep your job . . . things get difficult. The core problem is lack of understanding. Lack of understanding makes innovation difficult. Completely failing to understand this, Ioannidis recommends something that would discourage new ideas: “We must routinely demand robust and extensive external validation—in the form of additional studies—for any report that claims to have found something new.”

Truly “bad science” has little to do with what Ioannides or Goldacre or any quackbuster talks about. Truly bad science is derivative science, science that fails to find new answers to major questions, such as the cause of obesity. Failure of innovation isn’t shown by any one study. Given the rarity of innovation, it is unwise to expect much of any one study. To see lack of innovation clearly you need to look at the whole distribution of innovation. Whether the system is working well or poorly, I think the distribution of innovation resembles a power law: most studies produce little progress, a tiny number produce large progress. The slope of the distribution is what matters. Bad science = steep downward slope. With bad science, even the most fruitful studies produce only small amounts of innovation.

Just as outsiders expect too much from professionals, they fail to grasp the innovative power of non-professionals. Mendel was not a professional scientist. Darwin was not a professional scientist. Einstein did his best work while a patent clerk. John Snow, the first person to use data (a graph) to learn the cause of an infection, was a doctor. His job had nothing to do with preventing infection. To improve innovation about health (or anything else), we should give more power to non-professionals, as I argued in my talk at the First Quantified Self Conference.

Thanks to Robin Barooah.

 

 

 

 

7 thoughts on “Conway’s Law and Science

  1. “the science they are criticizing may be the best those professional scientists can produce, given the system within which they work. ”

    Are you familiar with the work of W E Deming ? Your remark here reminded me strongly of his statement on Quality (in the context of industrial production) that it is c 96% determined by the system in which the worker is working, and c4% by the worker. Hence, if you want to improve quality, you should focus on improving the system. Sounds to me like Science is the same.

  2. The best supported widespread cause of obesity I know of is the one that very strongly correlates antibodies to a particular rhinovirus with obesity. Unless somebody can show that only obese people catch that cold, or that only obese people continue to express that antibody, it really looks as if this particular cold actually leaves a propensity to obesity in its wake.

    The mechanism remains unknown Does it cause addiction to fructose? Reduced metabolic rate? Increased muscle pain after exercise? Insatiety? Your guess is as good as mine, maybe better. I wonder if anybody is actually looking into it, as a day job. The best we can do now is to stay away from fat people suffering colds.

  3. Nathan, staying away from fat people with colds won’t help you. If the theory is correct, the crucial cold happened before the person got fat.

    In fact, if the theory that you become immune to the specific rhinoviruses which have made you sick in the past, then it’s slightly more risky to be around thin people with colds than fat people with colds.

  4. I agree, especially with this:

    Making a life of debunking creationists and homeopaths does not lead to anything new and innovative, nor does it lead to a better understanding of evolution and disease.

    I also like your comparison of creation science and climate science.

    I would add two things. One is that having a job pushes the job holder toward playing it safe. Playing it safe and science don’t work well together, as you say. The other is that rules and regulations about science, ostensibly for the benefit of the public, flourish and grow (“IRB mission creep”) because jobs are created to enforce them. The more paperwork the bureaucrats can generate, the more people they can hire to process the paperwork, the larger their budget, and the more important they feel. This is a disaster for the public, which has no idea of the deadening effect of IRBs.

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *